The Wisdom of Crowds is an analysis of group dynamics and decision-making. James Surowiecki, the author, makes the case that groups usually make better decisions than individuals, including individual experts.
Bullet Summary
- Collective wisdom is, in many instances, superior to the individual wisdom of even the biggest expert
- There are important limitations of crowd wisdom, most of a sociological nature, that we must be aware of
- We can leverage collective wisdom with decentralized systems designed to take advantage of crowd-sourced decision-making
Summary
James Surowiecki is a journalist, and former staff writer at The New Yorker, where he wrote the “Financial Page” column.
He was previously at Slate, a publication whose articles I often enjoyed.
Obviously, Surowiecki lacks a background in sociology or psychology, but that, in my opinion, means little if one takes care of his own education.
#1. Crowds Make Better Decisions Than Individuals
The central theme of “The Wisdom of Crowds” is stated somewhat before the start
James Surowiecki uses several examples to make his point, including:
- A crowd guessing the weight of an ox better than any individual in the crowd did (full story here)
- A group of people guessed the location of a lost submarine better than any single individual in the group
- The crowd of “Who Wants to Be Millionaire” provided better answers than any single expert
Surowiecki goes even further by saying that crowds make better decisions if they are composed of not-so-knowledgeable and not-so-smart agents.
He says:
What Page found was that a group made of smart agents and not-so-smart agents almost always did better than groups made of only smart agents.
Page is Larry Page, and the author attributes the success of Google to Google tapping into the wisdom of crowds.
The problem with intelligence or knowledge is that intelligent or knowledgeable people tend to resemble each other, and the difference in perspectives decreases.
That doesn’t mean that intelligence or knowledge are irrelevant: they are not irrelevant, and they’re both crucial traits.
But it does mean that diversity is, indeed, extremely valuable.
#2. The Proof That Crowds Are Smart
The author says that the fact that very few people can beat the market is proof that the crowd is very good at making decisions.
If so few people can beat the market, why do we cling to the idea that the right expert will save us?
My Note:
It’s a good question, indeed. But I’m not convinced about this analysis: all the big funds in the market are led by experts.
Most money in the market is managed by experts.
So the stock market is not a good example of an “average crowd”.
Quoting “Fooled by Randomness,“ the author also says that those who eventually beat the market are rarely beating the market because of their expertise but are simply the product of randomness.
#3. You Need 5 Elements For A Wise Crowd
Not all crowds are wise, and, as we shall see, some of them are irrational and plainly do stupid stuff.
Here are the 5 elements that are necessary for a wise crowd:
- Diversity of Opinion: individuals must draw different backgrounds and beliefs and base their opinions on private information
- Independence: individuals opinion must be independent and not swayed by the group
- Decentralization: decentralized systems allow an individual to draw on local knowledge and react faster
The top three are the conditions for a group to be “intelligent” and reach wise conclusions.
To make the group functional and to keep working, the system also needs:
- Aggregation: there must be a system that aggregates the decentralized individuals’ private judgment into collective wisdom
- Trust: each individual must trust that the group is fair and that punishment is handed out for rule-breakers
#4. Limitations of Wisdom of Crowds
The author also goes into sociology and social psychology.
He talks about herd behavior and a few well-known sociological experiments.
And he says:
If too many people adopt the same strategy, then the strategy stops being sensible and the crow stops being smart.
Herd Savior: Overconfident People
A cascade of information is what leads to herd behavior, even if we are not in the physical presence of a group.
A cascade of information is made possible by people who value public information more than private information.
That’s where overconfident people come in handy: they value their own personal information and conclusions more than the group’s conclusions. They make the public’s information seem less certain, and they encourage others to question the group’s conclusions.
#5. To make cooperation work you need conditional consenters
When it comes to cooperation, we can differentiate among different kinds of individuals.
The author quotes Fehr and Gaetcher (Fehr and Gächter, 2000) saying that:
- 25% of people are selfish, -or “rational” in economic terms-
- a small minority are altruists, who contribute no matter what
- the biggest groups are conditional consenters
The secret to getting a cooperative group going is to engage the conditional consenters.
And that’s the problem of many public good games: by the end of it, most conditional consenters are no longer cooperating.
#6. Cooperation Problems in Tax System
James Surowiecki ends up discussing topics that have little to do with “wisdom of the crowds” but that are equally, if not more, interesting.
He talks about taxes as an example of a cooperation problem.
For a group to cooperate, he says, people must feel that:
- Trusting others: people are happy to chip in as long as they know that others are doing the same (contingent consenters)
- Trusting the government: to spend the taxes wisely and for the public good
- Certainty of punishment: people feel like the system does not work if cheating does not get punished
My Note:
This is very good social psychology
#7. Vindicative Players Make The World Fairer
The author delves much into behavioral economics and talks about the willingness of people to punish bad behavior even when it will cost them to do so (a subset of “strong reciprocity“).
He says that even if people don’t do it for the common good, the result is the same: strong (and vindicative) reciprocators help make the world a fairer place.
Says the author:
Individually irrational acts can produce a collectively rational outcome
I really loved this part, as I always thought the same.
#8. Hierarchies & Power Dynamics Thwart Group’s Wisdom
Groups can also thwart collective wisdom by virtue of the power dynamics inherent in every group.
For example, you get the most dominant person to speak the most, albeit he might not necessarily be the most knowledgeable person.
And the more he speaks, the more people consider him credible and trustworthy, which, again, can only compound the original problem.
More Golden Nuggets
- Science is cumulative, every scientist builds on other people’s work
- The healthiest markets are dominated by fear and greed at the same time: only with different and opposing attitudes can the market function well
- Less information is more: traders with too much information make wrong choices because we tend to give too much weight to the news
- Herd mentality in physical groups is what turns a crowd into a mob
- In any crowd, there are some people who’d never riot and some who’d always riot (instigators). The majority joins if the instigators reach the tipping point, and when a riot starts, the instigators shape the collective behavior
The Wisdom of Crowds Quotes
On the paradox of the wisdom of crowds:
Paradoxically, the best way for a group to be smart is for each person in it to think and act as independently as possible.
Talking about the crowds of “Who Wants to Be A Millionaire”:
The experts did OK (65%). But they paled in comparison to the audiences. Those random crowds of people with nothing better to do on a weekday afternoon than sitting on a studio picked the right answer 91% of the time.
Talking about the wisdom of the crowd when the crowd has little knowledge to make a choice:
At the height of the Cold War half of all Americans thought the Soviet Union was a member of NATO.
Is it really plausible that Americans voters will really make sensible policy choices?
That says a lot about democracy :).
Criticism
There is some criticism in this otherwise good book. Some of it I found online and agreed with, and some of it I am moving myself:
1. Statistical sampling in disguise, not crowd wisdom
Once you add all the “exceptions” to the “wisdom of the crowd,” it seems more like the author is talking about statistical sampling than real-life group interactions.
2. Little criticism of distributed intelligence systems
The author makes the case that the wisdom of the crows works best with distributed intelligence systems where different people chip in, like Wikipedia, for example.
However, he does not mention the problems of such systems. It’s been the case, for example, that knowledgeable writers on Wikipedia have been corrected by less knowledgeable people and couldn’t manage to get the truth across.
The idea that collective wisdom outweighs experts also presents counter-examples, like, for example, Kasparov beating “the rest of the world” in the chess match “Kasparov VS The Rest of The World“.
The crowd might also be poor at coming up with totally new ideas as the outliers get pulled back into the average of known and more popular solutions.
3. Some unscientific “proof”
The author says that when the Challenger burned, the stock market “knew” which company was at fault, even though there was no official information as to which of the many contractors was to blame.
That’s just silly.
So what now, we go from “crowd wisdom” to a crowd of fortune tellers?
4. Honesty developed because it’s profitable?
The author discusses some history of capitalism as well.
He makes the point that capitalism is built on trust and that we trust each other much more than we think we do (ie.: trusting that a tech product you buy online or at a shop is a huge act of trust).
He is right, but I don’t agree with his conclusion that trust develops because it’s profitable.
That would entail everyone making a rational decision and sticking to it.
And people don’t really work like that.
5. If scientific replication fails you should doubt yourself?
The author suggests that if a replication study fails, then you should righteously doubt your own experimentation skills and not the original study.
I find that concept misguided and at the root of the herd behavior that the author himself discusses.
The fact that an experiment has been successful doesn’t mean it was “correct’ or that it describes universal truth, as has been made abundantly clear by the current replication crisis.
6. Some misunderstanding of how markets work
The author says that the hedge fund Long Term Capital Management was operating on illiquid assets and making very little money on each trade “vacuuming up nickles”.
But, he says, they made lots of money thanks to leverage.
But that doesn’t make sense to me, because more leverage in small markets with small differences in prices will not make you earn lots of money.
When the trading volumes are too small, more leverage is not helpful.
7. The Crime Against Italy
LOL this party had me laughing as I could see myself in the author’s description.
He is referring to Italy losing to South Korea in the 2002 World Cup.
It was one of the best Italian teams ever, with the defensive line being possibly the very best ever (Buffon, Nesta, Maldini, Cannavaro, anyone who knows football could hardly disagree on the quality of those guys).
The author says that the Italians made up the conjure.
But no proof of corruption does not mean there was no corruption.
I personally still remain open to the idea that the match might have been fixed, and time has proven that referee Moreno does not shy away from illegal activities.
The author also defends the referee’s background, saying he’s been a FIFA official referee for years.
But says little, also considering FIFA’s CEO Blatter, is a notorious scumbag.
Review
The Wisdom of Crowds has relatively low reviews, and I don’t see why.
In many ways, what the author describes is similar to the system Ray Dalio uses in Bridgewater that he describes in his highly acclaimed book “Principles“.
I found “The Wisdom of Crowds” to be insightful in many ways. Its central tenet is controversial, but it’s well explained and it makes sense.
It’s not super strong when it comes to actual research because the beautiful anecdotal stories mean little in terms of proof.
Yet, the author is sometimes, -but not always- is also the first to criticize and expose the limitations of his own examples.
I can say that I really learned a lot from “The Wisdom of Crowds“.
Particularly, it made me less of an extremist in my critical approach to crowds and groups. And I am thankful for that.
In a nutshell, I have reservations about some of the claims, but I can still highly recommend “The Wisdom of Crowds” to any social scientist and to anyone who’s interested in learning about people.
Also read: